It has come to our attention that certain coaching centers are misusing names similar to ours, such as Vajirao or Bajirao, in an attempt to mislead and attract students/parents. Please be informed that we have no association with these fake institutes and legal proceedings have already been initiated against them before the Hon'ble Delhi High Court. We urge students and parents to stay vigilant and let us know in case they are approached by such fake institutes.

Why the Government is Selling Wheat and Rice at Higher Prices despite Surplus Stocks

18/07/2025

However, with large reserve of grain, India increased the prices of wheat and rice in the open market to able with the inflation as well as recovering costs and being able to secure food in the long term.

Selling wheat and Rice

The situation of food-grains in India in 2025 seems to have a peculiar paradox: on the one hand, historical high yields and overflowing granaries with high grain stocks, on the other hand, planned increase in the open market sale prices of wheat and rice. Why such pricing regulations are being implemented when grain is being produced in large quantities, the questions among the stakeholders stand as the Food Corporation of India (FCI) has risenby almost eleven percent. Generally, the availability of surplus in the market means that market prices are likely to reduce and thus, government interventions become more consumer-oriented. Nevertheless, the change of policy this year posits a more serious economic and strategic reasoning.This article dwells upon the multiple justifications of the policy of the government. It determines the impact of inflation control, fiscal revival, and balance in the long-term buffer stock on these actions, rather than be based on supply measures alone. It also explores the consequences to farmers, traders, and millers and to consumers, hence evaluates whether the pricing policy is consistent with more general objectives of sound food policy, market efficiency and the general welfare. The discussion does so to provide a subtle approach on how surplus can also be utilized not only to meet current demands but also to influence strategic outcomes in the Indian food economy.

Contextual Background

The increase of the reserve price of wheat and rice by India in case where the quantity is supplied over and above the demand can be well explained in Indian institutional and historical backgrounds of procurement, storage and interventions in the open markets.

Mechanism in stocking and Government Procurement
The most fundamental pillar of India food security architecture is the procurement mechanism centredon the Minimum Support Price (MSP) for wheat. Wheat and rice are mainly bought by the FCI and state agencies. These purchases are added to the central pool and this funds program such as the Public Distribution System (PDS). Strategies of buffer norms are also kept to stabilize markets and to have availability in lean season. There has been an increase in the number of procurement over the years even going to the extent of surpassing the buffer needs indicating policy-propelled procurement as well as bumper harvests.

Storage and Distribution Framework
After being acquired, food-grains are stored within hired testing warehouses as well as FCI-controlled warehouses. Despite the increased quality of digital stock management, it can be expensive to store long term due to aging infrastructure and increased costs of logistics. This subjects pressure on urgent market liquidation of stocks. Part of it is through the welfare schemes but excess usually needs to be monetized through Open Market Sale Schemes (OMSS) when the granaries are full to capacity. In such a manner, the sale pricing is not only a lever toward releasing the stocks but also to recoup the operational expenses.

Development of Open Market Sale Scheme (OMSS)
Presented as a tool of strategy, OMSS enables the government to sell surplus supplies to the independent merchants, flour factories and institutions. In the past, the prices would be set at lower prices than what was prevailing in the market in an attempt to reduce inflation and help in maintaining the supply. Nevertheless, recent changes indicate a more financially oriented attitude: the prices of the reserves have been adjusted to the increase in costs and the expansion of wider economic indicators. It symbolizes a break in OMSS since it moves the subsidy tool to calibrated market intervention device.

Economic Reason Behind

There is actually nomismatch of supply as is heard in India: decision to increase the reserve price of wheat in the Open Market Sale Scheme (OMSS) even though there was surplus wheat elsewhere, was a strategic balance within inflation, costs and global indicators.

Management of inflation and Market stabilization
Surplus production normally pushes down retail prices posing threat of compromising incomes of farmers. This will cause the government to set a higher reserve price so that the market prices do not crash drastically especially during lean procurement regions. This action stabilizes price anticipation, protects farmers against strained sales and normalizes unpredictability within wholesale markets. It also gives a green flag on the confidence of India in its grain ecosystem and thus mitigates speculative trade and panic hoarding.

Recovery of Cost and Fiscal Prudence
It does not cost free to hold and preserve grain supply. An increase in transportation costs, warehouse overheads and maintenance of quality costs has burdened the budget of FCI. The government ameliorates these costs by increasing the reserve price and OMSS does not turn out to be a fiscal cost. Basically, the approach transforms OMSS to a revenue conflicts device without defeating food supplies to welfare programs.

Comparing with Price Movement across the World
The price of wheat and rice has experienced a fluctuation in the international markets caused by climate shocks and export restrictions as well as geopolitical issues. The pricing strategy accepts all these trends by not losing to arbitrage and making domestic sales that are more competitive. The reserve price, through close monitoring of international indices, signals not only a local policy direction but also a hedge against international market interference particularly in cross border trade conditions.

policy for open ecosystem

Political and Strategic Aspects

This move is not simply economic, but it lies deep-rooted in the political arithmetic of the government, fiscal messaging and medium-term fiscal and food security management strategy, administration and efficiency.

Electoral Optics and Subsidy Funds
Price changes are monitored on the eve of an election. Although there may be populist tendencies in having cheaper grain available to consumers, such a step would show financial restraint on the part of the government and would value the long-term sustainability. High reserve prices crop out the increasing subsidy loads and still leave room to run targeted welfare programs such as the PMGKAY. This will strengthen the story of responsible rule without depriving vulnerable groups of food.

The Indirect Pricing Mechanism to Give Support to Farmers
The level of MSP is not increased, but the open market prices of the reserves are relatively higher, hence leading to price realization among farmers indirectly by averting market surpluses. Selling of the excess stock at a low price is an act that runs the risk of undercuttingmandi prices. Having an upper boundary on floor price prevents a downward spiral in farm gateprices so that farmers profit with a bumper harvest and do not sell in distress.

Tactical Buffer Stock Adjustment
It is important to make sure that there are vibrant buffer stocks, not just in delivering PDS but in resolving any climate volatility and geopolitical shocks. Calibrated prices facilitate controlled offloading of excess stock instead of indiscriminate offloading of excess stock, as might be the case. In a world of uncertainties and being affected in the food supply chain, strategic conservation usingrelease at a controlled rate allows India to maintain its independence in grain diplomacy and emergency management.

Effect on Stakeholders

With the new OMSS policy on grain pricing, India is redefining the food economy of its people-in both an explicit and a more nuanced sense-reaching the millers, traders, farmers, and the consumers.

Millers and Traders
OMSS auctions commonly consist of first-line buyers who are private tradesmen and flour operators.

  • The increased reserve price increases what they pay to operate and hence makes it hard to operate, so there is due diligence in procuring.
  • The smaller players will either be priced out of business or have to look elsewhere, but the big pro processors may still be able to absorb the cost, hedging by long-term contract or by planning.
  • The change transforms the market participation, which becomes more comfortable with scale and financial flexibility than agile.

Farmers’ Interests
Though farmers do not directly buy under OMSS, they are indirectly involved.

  • High maximum reserve price eliminates oversupply problems in the market in depressing mandi rates, particularly during post-harvest times.
  • This plays a role in cushioning farm earnings against the unpredictability of releasing surplus stock.
  • The government controls downstream price disruption, thereby providing a cushion that prevents the escalating distress in the countryside, which further adds to the usefulness of the PPS.

Consumers and Welfare recipients
The increased OMSS price will not have a direct price shock on the consumers and in particular, the beneficiaries of the PDS.

  • Under subsidized entitlements, subsidized products are not counted, and welfare grain is distributed independently of activity in the open market.
  • Nevertheless, the retail prices might be pushed upward to the non-PDS consumers where the products are wheat-based.
  • The phased release plan and unsold granaries always provide a leeway to relax the supplies in the event of unanticipated inflationary outbreaks.
stackholder impact matrix

Criticisms and Counterpoints

The increase of the reserve price of wheat has elicited controversy among various stakeholders byraisingmany question marks.

Market Access Risks and Exclusion Risks
The reservation of the criticism is that the increased prices in reserve may exclude smaller purchasers, particularly in areas where personal procurement is essential. Increasing the price floor, a government may jeopardize the participation of the OMSS auction by the local millers or small-scale traders unable to compete with new benchmarks. This has the potential to destabilize market diversity and cause regional imbalance in grain supplies, especially in underserved regions.

Transparency of Policy
The other issue is to do with the lack of transparency of OMSS activities. Stakeholders have raised the issue of how the auction volumes should be determined, how areas can be allocated, and to whom the buyers should be able to access the auction. Unless there is a transparent structure, the system may lose trust because of claims of inefficiency or favouritism. Activists are asking for improved disclosure by way of better disclosures by the industries and a decentralized allocation policy, keeping in view the local demand-supply conditions.

Efficiency or Welfare Debate
Critics of the price increaseamong economists argue that the price increase places fiscal recovery above the overall welfare goals. Though cost recovery and monetization of stocks are relevant, these initiatives should not trickle down to the affordability of food (especially by the non-PDS consumers). Others claim that a dual-pricing model or flexible pricing of the reserves might provide a healthier balance between economic reasoning and social justice.

Conclusion

Such a move by India of increasing the reserve price of wheat and rice when there were full granaries demonstrates a new geostrategy of not managing its surplus reactively but proactive in aligning its policies. Instead of the hasty sellingoff of stocks, the government is adjusting itseconomic cues: the inflation-fighting measures, a sustainable fiscal environment, and long-term food security. Although there is a dispute over the pricing strategy, there are also lightly hidden advantages, including stabilized farm incomes, minimized unintentional spillovers to subsidies, and in linewith domestic policies to worldwide tendencies. But the step is a smooth implementation and balanced reaction to stakeholder interest. The dynamic pricing, as well as improved OMSS outreach, will be necessary to ensure Equitable Access at a time of recovering costs. This is ultimately not a mere change of price, but a multi-faceted attempt to transform India'sFood Grain Economy to a resilient, balanced, and visionary management. Such policy sophistication is not only desirable but essential, as the climate variability and geopolitical tensions, as well as population pressures, continue to be on the increase.

Blogs